A brilliant post by guest
blogger Scott Sumner on Econlog (Econolog.econolib.org, April 21, 2014) : "Why the EMH is truer than supply and demand."
It is well worth reproducing it in full:
"My previous post
discussed the strangeness of the efficient markets hypothesis. Here I'll defend
its utility.
In the
field of economics, all models represent simplifications of reality. Thus when
we consider whether the EMH is true, it makes no sense to compare it to
something like Newtonian physics. Yes, even Newtonian physics is only
approximately true, but the approximation is much better than almost anything
we observe in economics. So let's compare apples with apples.
Supply and
demand has become the archetype model of economics. It's a workhorse widely
used to explain the behavior in all sorts of markets, from haircuts and dry
clearers to automakers and PC producers. Of course if you read the fine print
the model is, strictly speaking, only applicable to a very restricted set of
markets, essential grain producers. But almost all economists use it in a much
wider range of applications, with justification. It's really, really useful.
But is it
true? One of the most important implications of S&D is that producers are
price takers. This assumption is what underlies the existence of a supply
curve. If firms are not price takers then no supply curve exists. You can't
have a supply and demand model without the assumption of firms being price
takers.
But are they price takers? Not really. The vast majority of firms,
even in highly competitive industries such as laundromats, dry cleaners and
pizza shops, could raise prices by 5% and still hold on to a substantial share
of their customers. Exxon might not be able to do so, but most small businesses
could. This means the supply and demand model is not literally
"true."
Fortunately,
S&D is incredibly useful, even if not strictly true.
I would
argue the EMH is truer that the S&D model. And by EMH I am actually only
talking about the assumption that asset price deviations from trend are
essentially unforecastable. Specific versions such as the CAPM may be flawed in
other ways. However I believe the random walk model is truer than S&D, and
also quite useful. But how can we test the EMH?
Many
academics look for "anomalies." This is asking both too much and too
little. Contrary to widespread belief, the EMH does not claim that a search of
20 million statistical patterns would fail to identify 1 million anomalies that
show non-random price movements at the 5% level, or 200,000 at the 1% level. On
the other hand, I'd also argue that it's asking too much of academics to
suggest they need to find get-rich-schemes that violate the EMH, it should be
enough to prove that at least someone has done so (say Warren Buffett.)
As an
analogy, an economist looking for signs that the most famous secret in
alchemy--turning lead into gold--had been discovered should not have to
identify the magic formula, but rather merely show that gold prices are
behaving in a way consistent with the fact that someone had discovered
this sort of chemical process.
Eugene Fama
understood that the only meaningful test of the random walk was to look for
evidence that others had found anomalies. The initial tests showed no evidence;
mutual funds excess returns were serially uncorrelated, whereas they would be
correlated if a subset of investors had found the magic formula. Later work
with Kenneth French slightly modified that conclusion. There was some evidence
of stock picking ability, but too small to overcome the expense ratios of
mutual funds. So now the EMH is only approximately true. But since it's a part
of economics, we should have known that all along. No economic model is
precisely true.
OK, but is
it useful? I see three uses:
1. For
ordinary investors, it suggests you'd want to stick to indexed funds.
2. For
academics, it suggests that asset prices contain the optimal forecasts, and
hence you should use something like TIPS spreads rather than the output of VAR
models when trying to identify the optimal forecast of inflation. And you
should use the response of asset markets to monetary policy announcements to
evaluate the effectiveness of programs like QE, not subsequent movements in the
economy.
3. For
policymakers, it suggests that central banks and/or bank regulators should not
try to identify bubbles. And that central banks should create and subsidize
NGDP future markets. And that SEC officials should actually pay attention when
whistleblowers bring in evidence that hedge fund returns are inconsistent with
the predictions of the EMH (i.e. the Madoff case.)
To
conclude, the EMH is a very useful model. It's also more true than the S&D
model, as the pricing power of firms in so-called "competitive
industries" where S&D is widely applied is actually much greater than
the excess returns identified by Fama and French.
From now on
any commenter who tells me the EMH is not true, should also tell me whether
they think S&D is true, and if so, why it's true."
No comments:
Post a Comment